Monday, January 28, 2008

Will Peak Oil Drive Relocalization?

Over the past week, Stuart Staniford and Sharon Astyk have written thought-provoking essays at The Oil Drum on the nexus of Peak Oil and relocalization, with Staniford suggesting that peak oil will not result in relocalization of agriculture because the industrialization of agriculture is a more efficient use of energy and is not practicably reversible, and Astyk rebutting that idea. I think that both essays make important points, but I would like to offer a third perspective: that we have insufficient information to reach a conclusion about when energy scarcity will result in relocalization of agriculture, but that we will likely cross this threshold in the not-too-distant future and should prepare accordingly.

Astyk’s main critique of Staniford’s essay is, while important, focused primarily on the somewhat dismissive and partisan language of “reversalism.” I agree with this critique, and will not rehash it here. This critique does not, however, address the core of Staniford’s argument that centralization and hierarchal organization in agriculture will stabilize or intensify in the face of rising energy prices.

In my view, the primary weakness of Staniford’s analysis is the hidden substitution of causation for correlation in the body of his argument. My own writings have often been criticized as lacking in scientific analysis of hard data, and I accept that as the price of trying to approach causation directly. Graphs of data points, such as those dominating Staniford’s analysis, can clearly convey correlation with some causal mechanism—say an increasing linear function—but do nothing to establish that causal relationship itself. These graphs do nothing to establish a causal relationship between, to use Staniford’s examples, labor per acre or profit margin per acre and oil price. It could be pure coincidence that they appear positively correlated, much like the Virgin Mary on a piece of toast. As importantly, such correlations provide no insight as to whether the current correlative relationship will continue as oil prices increase—a small segment of a linear function, an exponential function, or a parabolic function may all fit this correlation, yet diverge wildly at later points. Here's an example: a graph showing the driving fatalities by age for 13 to 17 year olds will show a remarkable positive correlation between higher deaths at higher ages. The implied causality in such a graph is that aging causes driving fatalities. Of course, with the benefit of a much broader perspective, additional data showing that driving fatalities begin to decline significantly after roughly the age of 25, and the knowledge that (in the U.S.) one can get a license to drive at age 16, an alternate likely causality arises. This is, essentially, my critique of Standiford's argument--that while correlation may suggest causation on the very limited data set available to us, we really don't gain any insight into what will happen--or what form of agriculture will be most efficient--at oil prices equivalent to $200, $300, or more dollars per barrel. At risk of pushing too far into the philosophical, Staniford's analysis places us in the equivalent of Plato's cave where all we can see is the 13-17 year segment of the driving fatality graph. I won’t belabor this point any further—Scottish philosopher David Hume said this far better than I could if anyone cares to delve deeper into this line of thought.

Suffice it to say that, if we reject this substitution of causation for correlation, we’re left with Staniford’s rather bald conclusion that “industrial farmers are extremely efficient, and there is no way to compete with them except by becoming one” based solely on the presumptive correlation between various agricultural data in very recent history with historical oil prices. I don’t find that convincing, but Staniford must be given his due—he presents a plausible case, and certainly one that doesn’t disprove itself.

I think that the best way to approach this problem is to try to locate actual causal relationships that either A) make centralization and hierarchy more efficient means of organizing agriculture in the face of rising energy prices, or B) make decentralization a more efficient means of organizing agriculture in the face of rising energy prices:

A. Why would centralization of agriculture increase efficiency?

1. Economy of place: It is more efficient to grow oranges in Florida than in a heated greenhouse in upstate New York (or, to use the classic example, wine in Portugal than in England).
2. Economy of scale: It is more efficient for one man to grow ten orange trees than ten men to each grow one for a variety of reasons.
3. Specialization of knowledge processes: A contributor to #2 above, but particularly important in the era of increasingly scientific and knowledge intensive farming—farmers can afford to specialize in farming, whereas people who are only part-time farmers cannot to the same degree.
4. Justification for intensive capital expenditure: An industrial farmer can justify the expense of a complex combine harvester that automates processes, whereas a small holder may not be able to.

B. Why would decentralization of agriculture increase efficiency?

1. Transportation & operation cost: decentralized farming has the potential to require transportation over shorter distances to market than centralized farming, and therefore less embodied energy cost. Likewise, tractors and combines use oil, whereas hoeing and hand weeding do not.
2. Superior suitability for sustainable operation: for now, decentralized agriculture seems more capable of maintaining topsoil and is more adaptable to varying water regimes.
3. Greater resiliency to black swan & gray sway events: decentralized agriculture is less susceptible to terrorism, is more likely to incorporate the biodiversity necessary to overcome disease, and may be more adaptable in the face of global warming.
4. Less exposure to capital cost creep: decentralized agriculture is less dependent on expensive machinery that is subject to increasing cost as the cost of manufacture and raw materials increase.

There are undoubtedly many more reasons on both sides—the intent here is to set up the following balancing problem, not to present an exhaustive list.

It becomes apparent that resolving the centralization vs. decentralization of agriculture dispute requires balancing these factors—more specifically, balancing these factors at a given cost of energy. I don’t think that it can be reasonably disputed that, at some cost of energy, it is more efficient to centralize agriculture.* As a hypothetical, if energy is free, there is no substantive barrier to total centralization of all agriculture. Likewise, I don’t think it can be reasonably disputed that, at some cost of energy, it is more efficient to decentralize agricultural production. As a hypothetical, if energy is so expensive as to be totally use-prohibitive to all parties (e.g. nothing but human labor is available), then centralization that requires food transportation of a greater distance than a human can walk before the food spoils, or that requires more calories for a human to transport to market than the cargo contains, is infeasible. Obviously, we are faced with the challenge of balancing centralization vs. decentralization for some real cost of energy between free and use-prohibitive.

This analysis also confronts some significant knowledge gaps. Centralized agriculture is currently engaged in practices that are widely considered non-sustainable. Industrial farming practices are rapidly depleting topsoil and rely on non-renewable chemical inputs. Conversely, methods of decentralized agriculture exist that are widely considered fully sustainable—permaculture, Fukuoka method, and John Jeavon’s biointensive method, just to name a few. It may well be possible to adopt industrial-scale methods that are equally sustainable, but the efficiency loss in doing so is unknown. It seems unfair to compare an unsustainable method with a sustainable one, but no data currently exists sufficient to bridge this gap. Another factor to be addressed is the opportunity cost of time spent in decentralized agriculture/horticulture. If there are abundant opportunities to earn high wages relative to food costs—something true in today’s Western economies, but uncertain at best in a future scenario of $300/barrel oil—then the opportunity cost of spending personal time laboring in a garden weighs heavily against decentralized agriculture. However, if there is massive unemployment and it isn’t possible for most to earn enough to buy necessary food due to the embodied cost of energy inputs, then it is more rational to spend time gardening no matter how efficient centralized agriculture is.

Furthermore, it is necessary to consider the sunk cost and subsidies supporting centralized agriculture. Just two examples:

- The trillion dollar infrastructure of highways necessary to support our centralized system has already been paid for (well, is still being paid for in many respects) whereas decentralized agriculture has no trillion dollar head start. This infrastructure is supported by ongoing maintenance paid for via distributed taxes, not by tax attached to the price of food or collected from individual farmers. At some cost of energy, maintaining such a system is no longer practicable, erasing this current advantage for centralized agriculture.

- The existing urbanization of America (just to cite one example) makes gardening impracticable for many, and is a relic of cheap food and the inexpensive transportation network capable of supporting urbanization. There is a great reluctance to relocate for the purpose of making gardening affordable now, but at some theoretical cost of food there is a tipping point where people would stream to small holdings, dramatically erasing this current advantage for centralized agriculture.

Hopefully I have highlighted the methodological difficulties in determining whether centralized or decentralized agriculture is more efficient at a given price of oil we have not yet reached—and therefore whether this historical process is likely to be “reversible” at some price. I’d love to tell you that, at $254/barrel, society will tip from centralized to decentralized agriculture. Clearly I can’t do that, and I submit that there is insufficient data for anyone to do so at this time (or, to demonstrate that the same won’t happen). What I will suggest is that it seems clear to me that, at some price of oil, decentralized agriculture will be more efficient. Price may actually be misleading on this point—if one accepts a general energy descent future (which I realize is a big *IF* for many), then demand destruction may prevent prices of energy from continuing forever upward. In such a scenario it will actually be “at some availability of surplus energy” where decentralization becomes more efficient. If one extrapolates any of the various gloomier future scenarios for world energy production often presented it seems very possible that this threshold may be crossed within a generation or two. And, when we reach this threshold, those who have prepared or transitioned early will be better situated. There are, without doubt, vast uncertainties here, but the precautionary principle suggests that we prepare for the possibility that this point comes sooner rather than later. Finally, I would suggest that there are benefits of decentralized agriculture that reach beyond mere calculations of price, profit, and meeting minimal nutrition requirements (see notes below). There are, after all, reasons why people go on vacation to Tuscany instead of Kansas.**

* What are our goals—is it merely to meet our minimal nutritional requirements, or to amass the most material possessions? Who benefits from centralized processes vs. decentralized, and what political structures to they tend to support and accrete? Are we seeking to maximize the mean or median fulfillment of human ontogeny? These are ultimately moral and philosophical questions, and ones that I will not attempt to answer here. I do, however, wish to draw the reader’s attention to the complexities raised by trying to address this dilemma while simultaneously balancing the benefits of centralization and decentralization. For more on centralization vs. decentralization, consider my essay “A Theory of Power.”

** For a discussion of Tuscan hill towns as a mode of decentralized coordination, consider my essay “The Hamlet Economy.”

16 comments:

rich said...

Hi Jeff

Good synthesis of Stuart and Sharon's arguments.

As a true fence-sitter, I see both centralized and decentralized agriculture systems in a higher energy future, mostly due to the "unfair advantages" (climate) that you touch on, as well as in planning. The recent article "Soylandia" talks about the integration of food and fuel farming in the Cerrado region of South America in a tightly linked way...even when petro diesel is too expensive to pour into a combine gas tank, Brazil's closely spaced, integrated processing capacity will probably be cranking industrial quantities of soy products out long after the American Midwest becomes a patchwork of hamlets vying for those Tuscan tourists...

Cheers

Rich

Jeff Vail said...

Rich-

I think that you raise an interesting point with the focus in Brazil to co-locate production components--there is a great deal of room to improve the resiliency of industrial agriculture to higher energy prices. I don't think there is enough room there to fundamentally tip the balance against localized production.

It's also worth pointing out that highly centralized, hierarchal production is certainly possible even in a much lower energy environment. History is full of examples--just to name one, slave-driven, centralized grain production in North Africa largely supplied ancient Rome with its calories. I think that the key here is that examples of centralized yet low-energy food production also tend to result in very low median standards of living (slave labor). This begs the question, at least in my mind, whether the mighty "American Consumer" presumes the maintenance of a high median standard of living, or whether extreme consumption by elites could maintain demand so long as the sum total of consumption remained the same?

Cherenkov said...

I think that the practice of dividing and averaging the baby is both messy and deadly. I've noticed a disturbing trend amongst the peak oil blogoshpere whereby everyone seems loathe to point out the obvious and the resulting obvious results of that obvious information. Everyone loves to say, "Gosh, shucky-darn, I sure do admire everyone here, and gee-whillickers, I can sure see good points in what everyone is saying...."

While the drive for improving everyone's self-esteem is nigh on into its dotage, I fail to see its utility.

We live on a sphere.

I think everyone can agree to that.

There is a limited supply of resources.

Again. Blanket agreement.

We will run out.

More head nods.

Now, here comes the tricky part:

Where will we have to end up?

Let's look at that big ole bell curve of fossil fuel usage. Yes, that big nasty hump is kinda intimidating and certainly a giant cliff is always more entertaining and scary than the flatlands that stretch out to either side. (You can see why people tend to emphasize those few years after the peak.) But the fact is, we are heading towards that flatland.

The question is, what lies out there in the flatlands, Kansas, as it were?

Well, given that there will be a lack of resources, I believe I can say without any disagreement there will be no fossil fuel economy.

What else?

Will there have been enough resources for population to have grown as it has in the past?

What will the population settle out to?

What kinds of destruction will have been visited on the population in the scramble for the remaining resources?

What is the optimal population level given the immense reduction in fossil fuel?

Can you reasonably believe that we will be living with 12 billion people on the planet with solar energy?

So.

Ultimately, we are heading towards a very low energy lifestyle.

The only real question is, how do we get there?

What do we want?

Do we want to squander the remaining cheap energy in an effort to "SAVE THE TECHNOLOGY," or do we want to use that cheap energy to do the hard work in preparation for a low energy society?

I would like my "Tuscan Hamlet" to be something other than the remnants of a vast unplanned collapse.

Jeff Vail said...

I agree--it seems blatantly obvious to me that we're headed toward a much lower energy future. Oddly, I (we) seem to be in the minority, ignorance being bliss and all that. It seems likely that if we keep stumbling forward as we are, the masses end up in the modern version of a slave/human-labor driven economy-not where I want to be, so I hope it is possible to persuade enough influentials to start moving in what I consider the more prudent direction. In my attempt to do so, it's generally been my experience that working "with" someone to change their minds in my favor is more effective than telling them "you're stupid and here's why." The latter tends to work well only when the party calling someone else stupid already has all the power...

Rice Farmer said...

I too find myself in agreement with Cherenkov. Staniford assumes that mechanized farmers will cover their increasing costs, and make a substantial profit, by means of efficiency and getting good prices for their produce. But at some point, too many people will be priced out of the food market, and you can guess what happens when there are hordes of hungry people: They will just start raiding the mechanized farmers' fields, not to mention ransacking grocery stores and graineries. As Dmitry Orlov points out, the system won't be reversed, it will just collapse.
http://cluborlov.blogspot.com/2008/01/on-fallacy-of-reversibility.html

Jeff Vail said...

I agree that massive, peer-polity hierarchal structures can't voluntary decide to reduce--their natural life-cycle is growth & collapse. I think Tainter does a better job articulating the mechanism at work here than Diamond (though Diamond's case studies are very valuable). See, e.g., Logic of Collapse. While I don't think society as an aggregate whole can voluntarily devolve into a series of small holdings, that doesn't prevent people from setting up a network of small holdings today, occupying the space in Antonio Negri's notion of "diagonal"--out of phase with, but existing in parallel to the collapsing hierarchy. These could, then, persist during collapse, and either provide effectively for their creators, and/or act as a kind of complexity safety net that preserves beneficial elements of society--something similar to the monastic networks in Western Europe after the disintegration of the Roman Empire and through the Dark Ages.

Rob said...

The Staniford article infuriated me. I didn't read the whole thing I admit, but what I read seemed like he ignored all the subsidies that Agribusiness gets and how they used subsidies to drive more truly efficient, smaller farmers out of business. Saniford might as well have been defending the mafia as a business model, in my eyes.

There are horse farms and chicken farms in my area, and the manure on their property is considered toxic waste. I remove it for free and compost it with discarded leaves, and then spread the compost on my fields. One man's toxic waste is another's fertilizer. Hauling manure and driving to the farmer's market is my only use of machinery. Otherwise, I use ONLY hand tools and my soil is much happier for it. I worked on a mechanized farm last summer nad the soil seemed crusty and abused.

I have an analogy for mechanized farming -- it's like keeping a fish aquarium in a milkshake blender, and turning on that blender a few times a year.

rich said...

Whoa....I hope I wasn't mistaken for a supporter of industrial ag!

As energy prices rise, there will be pockets of industrial agriculture that remain longer than the average...not so different from a rise in sea level filling the valleys first, then the uplands.

I brought up the Brazil example because, barring a black swan event, they will be industrially producing far past the point of viability for most other regions, due to their co-located facilities, cheap labor, and favorable climate. Whether the result will be sustainable, or just, well, I have my doubts.

This would complicate the 'all fall down' collapse scenario...even if most Americans take to grubbing potatoes in their front lawns, soy products (I'd think plastics, most likely) could still be available. Just not at Wal Mart.

Likewise, whether the American consumer will be any position to be purchasing these products would be a valid question.

Jeff Vail said...

There's a parallel discussion on this essay currently at The Oil Drum:

http://www.theoildrum.com/node/3554

kwark said...

I thought Staniford's argument interesting as a purely academic exercise but likely to apply only in a supply and distribution environment that is stable and predictable. IMO, price increases are only the preface to the story of fuel scarcity. Along with price increases will likely be supply disruptions, unpredictable in their frequency and duration. We had a taste of this in the 70's so I don't think it's fear-mongering. If I'm even close to being correct, Staniford's argument for centralized efficency falls apart. Visualize semi-truck trailers full of perishables, baking in a Mid-western summer's sun, waiting for the truck-stop's overdue fuel shipment.

Artemisa's Granddaughter said...

Excuse me gentlemen. Please do not use Cerrado soybeans as an example of the efficiency of industrial agriculture solutions.

At this very moment indigenous peoples of the Cerrado are fighting this as an abuse of their habitat.

Peak oil isn't the only thing happening on the planet you know.

fdg said...

I like your blog. Thank you. They are really great . Ermunterung ++ .
Some new style Puma Speed is in fashion this year.
chaussure puma is Puma shoes in french . Many Franzose like seach “chaussure sport” by the internet when they need buy the Puma Shoes Or nike max shoes. The information age is really convenient .




By the way ,the nike max ltd is really good NIKE air shoes ,don’t forget buy the puma mens shoes and nike air max ltd by the internet when you need them . Do you know Nike Air Shoes is a best Air Shoes . another kinds of Nike shoes is better . For example , Nike Air Rift is good and Cheap Nike Shoes .the nike shox shoes is fitting to running.



Spring is coming, Do you think this season is not for Ugg Boots? maybe yes .but this season is best time that can buy the cheap ugg boots. Many sellers are selling discounted. Do not miss . Please view my fc2 blog and hair straighteners blog.
.thank you .


I like orange converse shoes ,I like to buy the cheap converse shoes by the internet shop . the puma shoes and the adidas shoes (or addidas shoes) are more on internet shop .i can buy the cheap nike shoes and cheap puma shoes online. It’s really convenient.
Many persons more like Puma basket shoes than nike air rift shoes . the Puma Cat shoes is a kind of Cheap Puma Shoes .
If you want to buy the Cheap Nike Air shoes ,you can buy them online. They are same as the Nike Air shoes authorized shop. Very high-caliber Air shoes and puma cat shoes . the cheap puma shoes as same as other.




polo shirts

ralph lauren polo shirts
chaussure puma

chaussure sport



chaussures puma

puma CAT

ed hardy clothing

ed hardy clothes



ed hardy womens

ed hardy sunglasses

fdg said...

http://wvvv6.spaces.live.com
http://pumashoes2009.spaces.live.com
http://buy-cheap-ugg-boots.blogspot.com
http://www.eshooes.com/cheap-shoes-show
http://good-puma.blogspot.com/
http://apps.facebook.com/faceblogged/?uid=1447786117

j said...

http://cid-f80137f6d1a8020b.spaces.live.com/?lc=2052
http://www2.atword.jp/sdgdyhd/
http://kurumaro.com/hardy/
http://hardyclothes.jugem.jp/
http://www.actiblog.com/sfawagfra/
http://thediary.org/cheaphandbags/
http://ameblo.jp/kaowy/
http://sale.edublogs.org/
http://www2.atword.jp/jak/
http://09handbags.blog126.fc2.com/
http://sun15.cocolog-nifty.com/
http://ameblo.jp/ailsa15/
http://junior2tennis.blog.shinobi.jp/

nike said...

http://www.shoesbuying.com/ : 2009 nike shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/2009-nike-shoes-c-153.htm : new nike shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/air-max-classic-bw-c-185.htm : Women's max
http://www.shoesbuying.com/mens-max-93-c-188.htm : Men's max 93
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-c-165.htm : nike shox
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-force-c-174.htm : Nike air force
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-2003-c-181.htm : Nike air max 2003
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-air-max-ltd-c-166.htm : nike air max ltd
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-air-max-tn-c-167.htm : nike air max tn
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-rift-shoes-c-162.htm : Nike air rift
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-yeezy-c-184.htm : Nike air Yeezy
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-airmax-c-154.htm : nike airmax
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-airmax-c-155.htm : Nike air max 90
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-airmax-c-157.htm : Nike air max 97
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-birds-nest-shoes-c-152.htm : nike birds nest shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-dunk-high-c-177.htm : nike dunk
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shoes-c-168.htm : nike RT1 shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-sb-c-180.htm : nike SB
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-shoes-c-156.htm : nike shox shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-shoes-c-158.htm : Nike shox OZ shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-shoes-c-159.htm : Nike shox R2 shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-shoes-c-160.htm : Nike shox R3 shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-shoes-c-163.htm : Nike shox R4 shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-shoes-c-164.htm : Nike shox R5 shoes
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-shox-c-171.htm : Nike shox TL3
http://www.shoesbuying.com/nike-trainers-lovers-c-118.htm : nike trainers lovers

http://www.racketsoffer.com/ : tennis rackets
http://www.racketsoffer.com/wilson-racquets-c-19/ : Wilson tennis rackets
http://www.racketsoffer.com/head-racquets-c-18/ : HEAD tennis rackets
http://www.racketsoffer.com/babolat-racquets-c-17/ : Babolat tennis rackets

theprophet said...

There was this guy who believed very much in true love and decided to take his time to wait for his right girl to appear. He believed that there would definitely be someone special out there for him, but none came.
Every year at Christmas, his ex-girlfriend would return from Vancouver to look him up. He was aware that she still held some hope of re-kindling the past romance with him. He did not wish to mislead her in any way. nike shoxsSo he would always get one of his girl friends to pose as his steady whenever she came back. That went on for several years and each year, the guy would get a different girl to pose as his romantic interest. So whenever the ex-girlfriend came to visit him, she would be led into believing that it was all over between her and the guy. nike womens shoes The girl took all those rather well, often trying to casually tease him about his different girlfriends, or so, as it seemed! In fact, the girl often wept in secret whenever she saw him with another girl, but she was too proud to admit it. Still, every Christmas, she returned, hoping to re-kindle some form of romance. But each time, she returned to Vancouver feeling disappointed.
Finally she decided that she could not play that game any longer. puma mens shoes Therefore, she confronted him and professed that after all those years, he was still the only man that she had ever loved. mens puma shoesAlthough the guy knew of her feelings for him, he was still taken back and have never expected her to react that way. He always thought that she would slowly forget about him over time and come to terms that it was all over between them. nike shox Although he was touched by her undying love for him and wanted so much to accept her again, he remembered why he rejected her in the first place-she was not the one he wanted. nike 360 air maxSo he hardened his heart and turned her down cruelly. nike running shoesSince then, three years have passed and the girl never return anymore. They never even wrote to each other. NIKE air shoes The guy went on with his life..... still searching for the one but somehow deep inside him, he missed the girl.
On the Christmas of 1995, he went to his friend's party alone. "Hey, how come all alone this year? Where are all your girlfriends? What happened to that Vancouver babe who joins you every Christmas?", asked one of his friend.nike air max He felt warm and comforted by his friend's queries about her, still he just surged on.
Then, he came upon one of his many girlfriends whom he once requested to pose as his steady. He wanted so much to ignore her ..... not that he was impolite,wholesale nike shoes but because at that moment, he just didn't feel comfortable with those girlfriends anymore. nike shox torchIt was almost like he was being judged by them. The girl saw him and shouted across the floor for him. Unable to avoid her, he went up to acknowledge her.
"Hi......how are you? Enjoying the party?" the girl asked.
"Sure.....yeah!", he replied.
She was slightly tipsy..... must be from the whiskey on her hand.